Should financial incentives be used to differentially reward 'me-too' and innovative drugs?
- PMID: 20014872
- DOI: 10.2165/11318770-000000000-00000
Should financial incentives be used to differentially reward 'me-too' and innovative drugs?
Abstract
Strategies to change the existing mix of innovative and 'me-too' drugs are intended to increase societal value of a given investment in R&D by providing an incentive for firms to invest in drugs that are more likely to be clinically innovative. How can financial incentives be used to change this mix? Will a strategy have its intended consequence or will it have the unintended outcome of reducing the rate at which the population burden of disease is reduced? The perspective of this review is a country such as Australia, Canada or the UK that has universal health insurance and a drug reimbursement process that is informed by economic evidence. A review of the literature was performed and the views of both the proponents and the opponents of such strategies and the mechanisms by which they could be implemented were summarized. The debate is based largely on hypothesized responses by firms to changes in incentives rather than empirical evidence. The main point of contention is whether a changed mix of new molecular entities (NMEs) increases or decreases the total amount of clinical innovation launched each year. The argument presented in this article is that, despite the limited empirical evidence, it is possible to improve our assessment of the likely costs and consequences of a proposed strategy by appealing to economic theory and observations about the reimbursement process. First, the empirical evidence supporting the view that changing a mix of drugs will improve clinical innovation is based on the average launched drug, not the marginal innovative drug otherwise not developed, and therefore could be misleading. Second, the dynamic and complex nature of evidence of clinical innovation will reduce the feasibility of using contractually based mechanisms to implement such a strategy. Also, a single country is unlikely to have an impact on R&D decisions, and variation in the per capita economic value of new drugs would make multi-jurisdiction contracts with one firm difficult to implement. Third, the quality of evidence of the clinical innovation of the lead drug could be reduced if there are fewer or no follow-on drugs. Finally, the existing inefficiencies in the process of displacement to finance new technologies from a capped budget reduces the efficiency with which any additional potential clinical innovation from NMEs will be translated to reduced population burden of disease. The article concludes that it is possible that such a strategy could be costly to implement, and the impact on global burden of disease uncertain in both direction and magnitude. This is likely to be the case even if the average clinical innovation content of innovative NMEs is higher than for me-too NMEs and the mechanisms designed to change the mix of NMEs are effective. Other options to improve the effectiveness with which pharmaceutical clinical innovation reduces burden of disease should be explored, including improved efficiency of both firm R&D and the process of disinvestment to finance new technologies.
Similar articles
-
Incentives and disincentives to drug innovation: evidence from recent literature.J Med Econ. 2019 Aug;22(8):713-721. doi: 10.1080/13696998.2019.1613240. Epub 2019 Jun 12. J Med Econ. 2019. PMID: 31038374 Review.
-
Private versus social incentives for pharmaceutical innovation.J Health Econ. 2016 Dec;50:286-297. doi: 10.1016/j.jhealeco.2015.12.003. Epub 2016 Feb 4. J Health Econ. 2016. PMID: 26944633
-
Analyses of direct and indirect impacts of a positive list system on pharmaceutical R&D investments.Clin Ther. 2013 Jul;35(7):941-9. doi: 10.1016/j.clinthera.2013.05.002. Epub 2013 Jun 24. Clin Ther. 2013. PMID: 23806327
-
Can patent duration hinder medical innovation.Int J Health Econ Manag. 2016 Dec;16(4):397-406. doi: 10.1007/s10754-016-9198-0. Epub 2016 Sep 2. Int J Health Econ Manag. 2016. PMID: 27878691
-
Can open-source drug R&D repower pharmaceutical innovation?Clin Pharmacol Ther. 2010 May;87(5):534-6. doi: 10.1038/clpt.2010.26. Clin Pharmacol Ther. 2010. PMID: 20407458 Review.
Cited by
-
Better informing decision making with multiple outcomes cost-effectiveness analysis under uncertainty in cost-disutility space.PLoS One. 2015 Mar 9;10(3):e0115544. doi: 10.1371/journal.pone.0115544. eCollection 2015. PLoS One. 2015. PMID: 25751629 Free PMC article.
-
Value of information and pricing new healthcare interventions.Pharmacoeconomics. 2012 Jun 1;30(6):447-59. doi: 10.2165/11592250-000000000-00000. Pharmacoeconomics. 2012. PMID: 22591129
-
Current landscape of innovative drug development and regulatory support in China.Signal Transduct Target Ther. 2025 Jul 22;10(1):220. doi: 10.1038/s41392-025-02267-y. Signal Transduct Target Ther. 2025. PMID: 40691459 Free PMC article. Review.
-
The value of innovation under value-based pricing.J Mark Access Health Policy. 2016 Apr 7;4. doi: 10.3402/jmahp.v4.30754. eCollection 2016. J Mark Access Health Policy. 2016. PMID: 27123192 Free PMC article.
-
An early indicator of drug success: Top Journal Selectivity Index.Drug Des Devel Ther. 2013;7:93-8. doi: 10.2147/DDDT.S37324. Epub 2013 Feb 13. Drug Des Devel Ther. 2013. PMID: 23430968 Free PMC article. Review.
References
Publication types
MeSH terms
LinkOut - more resources
Full Text Sources