Skip to main page content
U.S. flag

An official website of the United States government

Dot gov

The .gov means it’s official.
Federal government websites often end in .gov or .mil. Before sharing sensitive information, make sure you’re on a federal government site.

Https

The site is secure.
The https:// ensures that you are connecting to the official website and that any information you provide is encrypted and transmitted securely.

Access keys NCBI Homepage MyNCBI Homepage Main Content Main Navigation
. 2012 Sep;180(3):296-305.
doi: 10.1086/667193. Epub 2012 Jul 25.

Synergy and group size in microbial cooperation

Affiliations

Synergy and group size in microbial cooperation

Daniel M Cornforth et al. Am Nat. 2012 Sep.

Abstract

Microbes produce many molecules that are important for their growth and development, and the exploitation of these secretions by nonproducers has recently become an important paradigm in microbial social evolution. Although the production of these public-goods molecules has been studied intensely, little is known of how the benefits accrued and the costs incurred depend on the quantity of public-goods molecules produced. We focus here on the relationship between the shape of the benefit curve and cellular density, using a model assuming three types of benefit functions: diminishing, accelerating, and sigmoidal (accelerating and then diminishing). We classify the latter two as being synergistic and argue that sigmoidal curves are common in microbial systems. Synergistic benefit curves interact with group sizes to give very different expected evolutionary dynamics. In particular, we show that whether and to what extent microbes evolve to produce public goods depends strongly on group size. We show that synergy can create an "evolutionary trap" that can stymie the establishment and maintenance of cooperation. By allowing density-dependent regulation of production (quorum sensing), we show how this trap may be avoided. We discuss the implications of our results on experimental design.

PubMed Disclaimer

Figures

fig 1
fig 1
Accelerating, decelerating, and sigmoidal benefit functions. A) Total benefit as a function of total public goods investment Nx, expressed as the product of the group size N and the cooperative investment per individual, x. The solid and dashed lines represent synergistic (accelerating) benefits as they have positive concavity for some intervals, whereas the dotted line always represents diminishing returns. B) Corresponding per-capita benefit B(Nx)/N as a function of group size, N, assuming that every individual cooperates at some fixed amount (here, x = 1, meaning full cooperation). The benefit functions used are B(x) = α(β + deκbx)−1α(β + deκ)−1 with α = 105, d = 1, β = 1, κ = 0, and b = 0.1 (decelerating benefits; dotted line), B(x) = bxa with b = 0.1 and α = 3 (accelerating benefits; dashed line), and α(β +deκbx)−1α(β + deκ)−1 where α = 90000, d = 1, β = 2, κ = 10, b = 0.2. (sigmoidal benefits; solid line).
fig 2
fig 2
Bifurcation plots illustrating the evolutionary dynamics with decelerating, accelerating, and sigmoidal benefit functions. The solid lines indicate the location of interior singular strategies for different group size N. Arrows indicate the direction of gradual evolution of a monomorphic population. A) Decelerating benefits. There is a unique evolutionarily stable strategy which decreases with group size. When group sizes are greater than approximately 80, cooperation is entirely disfavored. (B(x) = α(β + deκbx)−1) − α(β + deκ)−1 with α = 2000, d = 1, β = 1, κ = 0, and b = 0.8) B) Accelerating benefits. For small group sizes there is a unique evolutionarily stable strategy corresponding to full defection. As the group size increases, full cooperation also becomes an evolutionarily stable strategy. Any interior singular strategy is repelling and decreases with group size, but never reaches zero. (B(x) = bxa with b = 0.1 and α = 3) C) Sigmoidal benefits. Up to two interior singular strategies are possible, one repelling and the other attracting. (B(x) = α(β + deκbx)−1α(β + deκ)−1 where α = 10000, d = 1, β = 2, κ = 7, and b = 0.3). Each convergent stable attractor could potentially be an evolutionary branching point. The cost function used is C(x) = cx with c = 5.
fig 3
fig 3
Evolutionary branching and the emergence of two coexisting strategies of full defection and full cooperation in a setting with sigmoidal benefits and non-linear costs. A) Bifurcation plot illustrating the effects of group size on directional selection for the function used in the other diagrams in the figure. B) A pairwise invasibility plot (PIP) illustrating the monomorphic evolutionary dynamics. There are two singular strategies at approximately x = 0.2 and x = 0.4 of which only the latter is convergence stable. Monomorphic populations with trait values above the first singular strategy will evolve towards the second singular to the singular strategy where they undergo disruptive selection and subsequently evolutionary branching. C) Individual-based simulation demonstrating evolutionary branching at approximately x = 0.4, thus corroborating the predictions from the PIP. The inserted panel shows the evolutionary dynamics for populations which initially have trait values lower than the first singular strategy at approximately x = 0.2; here investment decreases to zero. D) Population dynamics of the resultant coexisting strategies of full defection (x = 0) and full cooperation (x = 1). If the fraction of cooperators is initially below approximately 18%, the cooperators will be eliminated altogether. Otherwise, the population dynamics will result in a stable coexistence with approximately 45% cooperators. The sigmoidal benefit function used is the same as in figure 1, B(x) = b(x3 + βx2)(x2 + α)−1, but with different parameters b = 200, β = 450, α = 180. The non-linear cost function used is C(x) = c1xc2x2 with c1 = 170, c2 = 50. The assumed group size in B-D is N = 30.
fig 4
fig 4
Effect of assortment (positive relatedness) on the evolutionary dynamics of decelerating, accelerating, and sigmoidal benefit functions. The different curves on each plot correspond to different degrees of others-only relatedness (which are equal to the values of 〈ρ〉): ro = 0, ro = 0.01, and ro = 0.5. Solid lines indicate attracting (convergence-stable) singular strategies, while dashed lines indicate singular strategies which are repelling (not convergence stable). Panels A, B, and C have use all the same benefit and cost functions as in figure 2.
fig 5
fig 5
Joint evolution of the public goods production trait x and the group-size threshold s, above which the production is expressed. Benefits and costs are as in figure 2C. At each generation, a group is formed of size 5 or size 45 with equal probability. For very low quorum sensing thresholds, production is not affected by changes in group size and evolution inevitably brings the production down to zero. However, for an intermediate range of the quorum sensing threshold s, public goods production can be stably maintained. This is true even if the threshold and production is allowed to co-evolve, provided that initial state is a population with an intermediate quorum sensing threshold and a sufficiently high production. For other initial conditions, co-evolution will bring the production down to zero and increase the threshold to arbitrarily large values.

Similar articles

Cited by

References

    1. Ajar É. Analysis of disruptive selection in subdivided populations. BMC Evolutionary Biology. 2003;3(1):22. - PMC - PubMed
    1. Ansaldi M, Dubnau D. Diversifying selection at the bacillus quorum-sensing locus and determinants of modification specificity during synthesis of the comx pheromone. Journal of bacteriology. 2004;186(1):15. - PMC - PubMed
    1. Archetti M. Cooperation as a volunteer’s dilemma and the strategy of conflict in public goods games. Journal of Evolutionary Biology. 2009a;22(11):2192–2200. ISSN 1420-9101. - PubMed
    1. Archetti Marco. The volunteer’s dilemma and the optimal size of a social group. Journal of Theoretical Biology. 2009b;261(3):475–480. ISSN 1095-8541. - PubMed
    1. Brännström Å, Dieckmann U. Evolutionary dynamics of altruism and cheating among social amoebas. Proceedings: Biological Sciences. 2005;272:1609–1616. - PMC - PubMed

Publication types