Skip to main page content
U.S. flag

An official website of the United States government

Dot gov

The .gov means it’s official.
Federal government websites often end in .gov or .mil. Before sharing sensitive information, make sure you’re on a federal government site.

Https

The site is secure.
The https:// ensures that you are connecting to the official website and that any information you provide is encrypted and transmitted securely.

Access keys NCBI Homepage MyNCBI Homepage Main Content Main Navigation
. 2013 Jun 19;8(6):e66199.
doi: 10.1371/journal.pone.0066199. Print 2013.

Contagion of Cooperation in Static and Fluid Social Networks

Affiliations

Contagion of Cooperation in Static and Fluid Social Networks

Jillian J Jordan et al. PLoS One. .

Abstract

Cooperation is essential for successful human societies. Thus, understanding how cooperative and selfish behaviors spread from person to person is a topic of theoretical and practical importance. Previous laboratory experiments provide clear evidence of social contagion in the domain of cooperation, both in fixed networks and in randomly shuffled networks, but leave open the possibility of asymmetries in the spread of cooperative and selfish behaviors. Additionally, many real human interaction structures are dynamic: we often have control over whom we interact with. Dynamic networks may differ importantly in the goals and strategic considerations they promote, and thus the question of how cooperative and selfish behaviors spread in dynamic networks remains open. Here, we address these questions with data from a social dilemma laboratory experiment. We measure the contagion of both cooperative and selfish behavior over time across three different network structures that vary in the extent to which they afford individuals control over their network ties. We find that in relatively fixed networks, both cooperative and selfish behaviors are contagious. In contrast, in more dynamic networks, selfish behavior is contagious, but cooperative behavior is not: subjects are fairly likely to switch to cooperation regardless of the behavior of their neighbors. We hypothesize that this insensitivity to the behavior of neighbors in dynamic networks is the result of subjects' desire to attract new cooperative partners: even if many of one's current neighbors are defectors, it may still make sense to switch to cooperation. We further hypothesize that selfishness remains contagious in dynamic networks because of the well-documented willingness of cooperators to retaliate against selfishness, even when doing so is costly. These results shed light on the contagion of cooperative behavior in fixed and fluid networks, and have implications for influence-based interventions aiming at increasing cooperative behavior.

PubMed Disclaimer

Conflict of interest statement

Competing Interests: The authors have declared that no competing interests exist.

Figures

Figure 1
Figure 1. Fluid network updates over time.
This figure shows the fraction of network update events in the fluid condition resulting in the formation of a new tie, the breaking of an existing tie, or no change to the network.
Figure 2
Figure 2. The contagion of cooperation.
This figure shows the probability of switching from defection to cooperation as a function of the percentage of neighbors that cooperated in the previous round, in the (a) fixed (b) viscous and (c) fluid conditions. Dots depict the percentage of individuals with the specified range of cooperating neighbors that switched to cooperation, and dot size is proportional to the number of observations. Error bars indicate standard error of the mean.
Figure 3
Figure 3. The contagion of defection.
This figure shows the probability of switching from cooperation to defection as a function of the percentage of neighbors that defected in the previous round, in the (a) fixed (b) viscous and (c) fluid conditions. Dots depict the percentage of individuals with the specified range of defecting neighbors that switched to defection, and dot size is proportional to the number of observations. Error bars indicate standard error of the mean.

Similar articles

Cited by

References

    1. Hardin G (1968) The Tragedy of the Commons. Science 162: 1243–1248. - PubMed
    1. Axelrod R (1984) The Evolution of Cooperation. New York: Basic Books.
    1. Fudenberg D, Maskin E (1986) The Folk Theorem in Repeated Games with Discounting or with Incomplete Information. Econometrica 54: 533–554.
    1. Ostrom E (1990) Governing the commons: The evolution of institutions for collective action: Cambridge Univ Pr.
    1. Nowak M, Sigmund K (1993) A strategy of win-stay, lose-shift that outperforms tit-for-tat in the Prisoner’s Dilemma game. Nature 364: 56–58. - PubMed

Publication types