Skip to main page content
U.S. flag

An official website of the United States government

Dot gov

The .gov means it’s official.
Federal government websites often end in .gov or .mil. Before sharing sensitive information, make sure you’re on a federal government site.

Https

The site is secure.
The https:// ensures that you are connecting to the official website and that any information you provide is encrypted and transmitted securely.

Access keys NCBI Homepage MyNCBI Homepage Main Content Main Navigation
. 2013 Jul 17;280(1766):20131475.
doi: 10.1098/rspb.2013.1475. Print 2013 Sep 7.

The excuse principle can maintain cooperation through forgivable defection in the Prisoner's Dilemma game

Affiliations

The excuse principle can maintain cooperation through forgivable defection in the Prisoner's Dilemma game

Indrikis Krams et al. Proc Biol Sci. .

Abstract

Reciprocal altruism describes a situation in which an organism acts in a manner that temporarily reduces its fitness while increasing another organism's fitness, but there is an ultimate fitness benefit based on an expectation that the other organism will act in a similar manner at a later time. It creates the obvious dilemma in which there is always a short-term benefit to cheating, therefore cooperating individuals must avoid being exploited by non-cooperating cheaters. This is achieved by following various decision rules, usually variants of the tit-for-tat (TFT) strategy. The strength of TFT, however, is also its weakness-mistakes in implementation or interpretation of moves, or the inability to cooperate, lead to a permanent breakdown in cooperation. We show that pied flycatchers (Ficedula hypoleuca) use a TFT with an embedded 'excuse principle' to forgive the neighbours that were perceived as unable to cooperate during mobbing of predators. The excuse principle dramatically increases the stability of TFT-like behavioural strategies within the Prisoner's Dilemma game.

Keywords: Prisoner's Dilemma; birds; cooperation; reciprocal altruism; tit-for-tat.

PubMed Disclaimer

Figures

Figure 1.
Figure 1.
A male pied flycatcher mobs a stuffed tawny owl. The mobbing flycatcher appears as a shadow. (Online version in colour.)
Figure 2.
Figure 2.
Number of pied flycatcher pairs that assisted their neighbours (unfilled bars) and those that remained at their own nests (filled bars) during the second trial in the absent-neighbour group and the defecting-neighbour group.

References

    1. Nowak MA. 2006. Five rules for the evolution of cooperation. Science 314, 1560–1563 (doi:10.1126/science.1133755) - DOI - PMC - PubMed
    1. Brandt H, Sigmund K. 2006. The good, the bad and the discriminator: errors in direct and indirect reciprocity. J. Theor. Biol. 239, 183–189 (doi:10.1016/j.jtbi.2005.08.045) - DOI - PubMed
    1. Wu JZ, Axelrod R. 1995. How to cope with noise in the iterated Prisoners-Dilemma. J. Confl. Resol. 39, 83–189 (doi:10.1177/0022002795039001008) - DOI
    1. Boyd R. 1989. Mistakes allow evolutionary stability in the repeated Prisoner's Dilemma game. J. Theor. Biol. 136, 47–56 (doi:10.1016/S0022-5193(89)80188-2) - DOI - PubMed
    1. Lotem A, Fishman MA, Stone L. 1999. Evolution of cooperation between individuals. Nature 400, 226–227 (doi:10.1038/22247) - DOI - PubMed

Publication types

LinkOut - more resources