Skip to main page content
U.S. flag

An official website of the United States government

Dot gov

The .gov means it’s official.
Federal government websites often end in .gov or .mil. Before sharing sensitive information, make sure you’re on a federal government site.

Https

The site is secure.
The https:// ensures that you are connecting to the official website and that any information you provide is encrypted and transmitted securely.

Access keys NCBI Homepage MyNCBI Homepage Main Content Main Navigation
. 2014 Jun 30:4:5491.
doi: 10.1038/srep05491.

Bluffing promotes overconfidence on social networks

Affiliations

Bluffing promotes overconfidence on social networks

Kun Li et al. Sci Rep. .

Abstract

The overconfidence, a well-established bias, in fact leads to unrealistic expectations or faulty assessment. So it remains puzzling why such psychology of self-deception is stabilized in human society. To investigate this problem, we draw lessons from evolutionary game theory which provides a theoretical framework to address the subtleties of cooperation among selfish individuals. Here we propose a spatial resource competition model showing that, counter-intuitively, moderate values rather than large values of resource-to-cost ratio boost overconfidence level most effectively. In contrast to theoretical results in infinite well-mixed populations, network plays a role both as a "catalyst" and a "depressant" in the spreading of overconfidence, especially when resource-to-cost ratio is in a certain range. Moreover, when bluffing is taken into consideration, overconfidence evolves to a higher level to counteract its detrimental effect, which may well explain the prosperity of this "erroneous" psychology.

PubMed Disclaimer

Figures

Figure 1
Figure 1
(a) Stable fraction of overconfident individuals fO in structured population and (b) equilibrium frequency of overconfident individuals x* in infinite well-mixed population as a function of resource-to-cost ratio r/c for different values of α and β. Data presented in Panel (a) are obtained by means of Monte Carlo simulations, while in Panel (b) are obtained by means of extended replicator dynamic (see Methods for details). Hollow symbols in Panel (a) and dash line in Panel (b) correspond to cases where bluffing does not exist (β = 0). Other parameters: fIO = 0.5, fB = 0.5.
Figure 2
Figure 2. The 3-D plots showing the stationary fraction of overconfident individuals fO in dependence on both α and β for (a) r/c = 1.5 and (b) r/c = 3.
The minimum fO is about 0.77 in Panel (a) showing that overconfidence is always favored under moderate values of r/c. When r/c is high, fO becomes more strongly dependent on the combination of α and β. The maximum fO is reached when both α and β are high, indicating that higher values of overconfidence is evolved in response to higher bluffing activities.
Figure 3
Figure 3. Influence of initial overconfidence level fIO and initial bluffing level fB on stationary fraction of overconfident individuals fO in the contour form.
Parameters are: α = 0.4, β = 0.3, and r/c = 2.5. Similar results can be obtained whenever α > β and r/c > 2.0. Overall, larger fIO corresponds to higher fO. For any given value of fIO, increasing fB further promotes fO, showing that overconfidence is favored when bluffing exists.
Figure 4
Figure 4. Typical snapshots of spatial patterns formed by different types of individuals under initial overconfidence levels fIO = 0.1 ((a)–(c)) and fIO = 0.3 ((d)–(f)) at different time steps.
Overconfident ones are colored blue (high real ability) and green (middle and low real ability). Unbiased ones are colored yellow (high real ability) and red (middle and low real ability). The stationary fractions of overconfident ones are 42.5% for fIO = 0.1 and 62.6% for fIO = 0.3. In structured population, high real ability but unbiased individuals form clusters to resist the invasion by overconfident ones, explaining the survival of unbiased ones even with high r/c. The size of the square lattices is 100 × 100. Other parameters: α = 0.4, β = 0.3, and r/c = 3.
Figure 5
Figure 5. Comparison of the payoffs of individuals with different real abilities.
(a) The 3-D plot showing the normalized average accumulated payoffs of individuals with high (H, crimson), middle (M, light green), and low(L, blue) real abilities respectively, as a function of fIO and fB. H ranges from 0.9350 to 1; M ranges from 0.4859 to 0.5521; L ranges from 0.0443 to 0.1065. (b) Average payoff ratio between the individuals who bluff and those who do not (R = Payof fbluff/Payof fnon–bluff) as a function of fIO and fB, when their real abilities are low (RL), middle (RM), and high(RH) respectively. RL ranges from 1.03 to 8.62; RM ranges from 1.01 to 1.634; RH ranges from 1.002 to 1.322. Data point is obtained by averaging over a period of 10000 time steps, and we have checked that longer time period does not qualitatively change the results. Other parameters: α = 0.4, β = 0.3, and r/c = 3.
Figure 6
Figure 6. Stable fractions of overconfident individuals fO and bluffing individuals fB as a function of r/c for different values of α and β, when players can learn both the overconfidence state and the bluffing state of others.
In Panel (a), α = 0.4 and β = 0.3. Bluffing prevails once r/c exceeds the critical value 2.0. Overconfidence does not drop to lower level with increasing r/c and remains above 0.89. In Panel (b), α = 0.7 and β = 0.6. Bluffing almost dominate the whole range of r/c. Overconfidence stays above 0.98 for r/c > 0.5. Other parameters: fIO = 0.5, and fIB = 0.5.

Similar articles

Cited by

References

    1. Taylor S. & Brown J. Positive illusions and well-being revisited-separating fact from fiction. Psychol. Bull. 116, 21–27 (1994). - PubMed
    1. Eisen C. Confidence: How winning streaks and losing streaks begin and end. Libr. J. 129, 67 (2004).
    1. Dunn D. S. A primer in positive psychology. J. Soc. Clin. Psychol. 27, 896–898 (2008).
    1. Pallier G. The role of individual differences in the accuracy of confidence judgments. J. Gen. Psychol. 129, 257–299 (2002). - PubMed
    1. Koehler J. The psychology of judgment and decision-making. Contemp. Psychol. 40, 315–316 (1995).

Publication types

LinkOut - more resources