Skip to main page content
U.S. flag

An official website of the United States government

Dot gov

The .gov means it’s official.
Federal government websites often end in .gov or .mil. Before sharing sensitive information, make sure you’re on a federal government site.

Https

The site is secure.
The https:// ensures that you are connecting to the official website and that any information you provide is encrypted and transmitted securely.

Access keys NCBI Homepage MyNCBI Homepage Main Content Main Navigation
. 2021 Apr;135(2):192-201.
doi: 10.1037/bne0000448.

The case against economic values in the orbitofrontal cortex (or anywhere else in the brain)

Affiliations

The case against economic values in the orbitofrontal cortex (or anywhere else in the brain)

Benjamin Y Hayden et al. Behav Neurosci. 2021 Apr.

Abstract

Much of traditional neuroeconomics proceeds from the hypothesis that value is reified in the brain, that is, that there are neurons or brain regions whose responses serve the discrete purpose of encoding value. This hypothesis is supported by the finding that the activity of many neurons covaries with subjective value as estimated in specific tasks, and has led to the idea that the primary function of the orbitofrontal cortex is to compute and signal economic value. Here we consider an alternative: That economic value, in the cardinal, common-currency sense, is not represented in the brain and used for choice by default. This idea is motivated by consideration of the economic concept of value, which places important epistemic constraints on our ability to identify its neural basis. It is also motivated by the behavioral economics literature, especially work on heuristics, which proposes value-free process models for much if not all of choice. Finally, it is buoyed by recent neural and behavioral findings regarding how animals and humans learn to choose between options. In light of our hypothesis, we critically reevaluate putative neural evidence for the representation of value and explore an alternative: direct learning of action policies. We delineate how this alternative can provide a robust account of behavior that concords with existing empirical data. (PsycInfo Database Record (c) 2021 APA, all rights reserved).

PubMed Disclaimer

Conflict of interest statement

Competing interests

The authors have no competing interests to declare.

References

    1. Allais M (1953). Le comportement de l’homme rationnel devant le risque: critique des postulats et axiomes de l’école Américaine. Econometrica: Journal of the Econometric Society, 503546.
    1. Ariely D, Loewenstein G, & Prelec D (2003). “Coherent arbitrariness”: Stable demand curves without stable preferences. The Quarterly journal of economics, 118(1), 73–106.
    1. Armel KC, Beaumel A, & Rangel A (2008). Biasing simple choices by manipulating relative visual attention. Judgment and Decision making, 3(5), 396–403.
    1. Azab H, & Hayden BY (2017). Correlates of decisional dynamics in the dorsal anterior cingulate cortex. PLoS biology, 15(11), e2003091. - PMC - PubMed
    1. Azab H, & Hayden BY (2018). Correlates of economic decisions in the dorsal and subgenual anterior cingulate cortices. European Journal of Neuroscience, 47(8), 979–993. - PMC - PubMed