Skip to main page content
U.S. flag

An official website of the United States government

Dot gov

The .gov means it’s official.
Federal government websites often end in .gov or .mil. Before sharing sensitive information, make sure you’re on a federal government site.

Https

The site is secure.
The https:// ensures that you are connecting to the official website and that any information you provide is encrypted and transmitted securely.

Access keys NCBI Homepage MyNCBI Homepage Main Content Main Navigation
. 2022 Sep 7;12(1):15157.
doi: 10.1038/s41598-022-18797-2.

The conditional defector strategies can violate the most crucial supporting mechanisms of cooperation

Affiliations

The conditional defector strategies can violate the most crucial supporting mechanisms of cooperation

Ahmed M Ibrahim. Sci Rep. .

Abstract

Cooperation is essential for all domains of life. Yet, ironically, it is intrinsically vulnerable to exploitation by cheats. Hence, an explanatory necessity spurs many evolutionary biologists to search for mechanisms that could support cooperation. In general, cooperation can emerge and be maintained when cooperators are sufficiently interacting with themselves. This communication provides a kind of assortment and reciprocity. The most crucial and common mechanisms to achieve that task are kin selection, spatial structure, and enforcement (punishment). Here, we used agent-based simulation models to investigate these pivotal mechanisms against conditional defector strategies. We concluded that the latter could easily violate the former and take over the population. This surprising outcome may urge us to rethink the evolution of cooperation, as it illustrates that maintaining cooperation may be more difficult than previously thought. Moreover, empirical applications may support these theoretical findings, such as invading the cooperator population of pathogens by genetically engineered conditional defectors, which could be a potential therapy for many incurable diseases.

PubMed Disclaimer

Conflict of interest statement

The author declares no competing interests.

Figures

Figure 1
Figure 1
The final numbers of cheaters (red dots) and cooperators (blue dots) at different group dispersal ranges: cheaters could thrive only when they started to share the dispersal costs to some degree. However, when the group dispersal range = 0, each cheater pays the dispersal costs by itself. Therefore, cheaters cannot arrange successful migrations and cannot violate the spatial structure mechanism. Hence, they encounter local extinction at their patches.
Figure 2
Figure 2
The runs that finished in favor of cooperators: (gray dots) most of these runs finished from 9000 to 30,000 steps by the complete extinction of cheaters, except one run reached the stop limit of our experiments at 50,000 steps, as three cheater agents succeeded to persist. The group dispersal range was 0 in all these runs. Therefore, cheaters cannot violate the spatial structure mechanism. The runs that finished in favor of cheaters by the complete extinction of cooperators: (1) (orange dots), runs finished after 8220 steps. (2) (green dots), finished from 5000 to 8220 steps. (3) (pink dots), finished before 5000 steps.
Figure 3
Figure 3
Different group dispersal ranges: (blue dots), group dispersal range = 30. (dark green dots), group dispersal range = 50. (sky blue dots), group dispersal range = 70. (light green dots), group dispersal range = 100. (orange dots), group dispersal range = 150. (red dots), group dispersal range = 200. Cheaters outcompeted cooperators in all of these runs. However, the extinction of cooperators is likely to be done more quickly, with fewer steps in the higher group dispersal ranges.
Figure 4
Figure 4
In the upper right, the frequencies of the greedy non-punishing agents through different experiments on three types of punishment: (1) Suspend harvest once (red dots). (2) Pay fine (green dots). (3) Kill (blue dots). The final frequencies of greedy non-punishing agents were above 90% in most runs (except one run for pay fine type was 88%). The mean frequencies of greedy non-punishing agents were above 80% for all runs. In the lower left, the frequencies of the other agents (brown dots): (1) Sustainable, punishing. (2) Sustainable, non-punishing. (3) Greedy, punishing.
Figure 5
Figure 5
A strong positive correlation between the variables (harvest greed and perception accuracy) through different punishment types: (1) The first type, "suspend harvest once" (small blue squares). The second type, "pay fine", is the same. (2) The third type "kill" (large orange squares). (3) The blue line is the linear relationship of the selected values through the first/second type of punishment. (4) The orange line is the linear relationship of the selected values through the third type of punishment.

References

    1. Ferriere R, Legendre S. Eco-evolutionary feedbacks, adaptive dynamics, and evolutionary rescue theory. Philos. Trans. R. Soc. B Biol. Sci. 2013;368(1610):20120081. doi: 10.1098/rstb.2012.0081. - DOI - PMC - PubMed
    1. West SA, Griffin AS, Gardner A. Evolutionary explanations for cooperation. Curr. Biol. 2007;17(16):R661–R672. doi: 10.1016/j.cub.2007.06.004. - DOI - PubMed
    1. Nowak MA. Five rules for the evolution of cooperation. Science. 2006;314(5805):1560–1563. doi: 10.1126/science.1133755. - DOI - PMC - PubMed
    1. Cremer J, Melbinger A, Wienand K, Henriquez T, Jung H, Frey E. Cooperation in microbial populations: Theory and experimental model systems. J. Mol. Biol. 2019;431(23):4599–4644. doi: 10.1016/j.jmb.2019.09.023. - DOI - PubMed
    1. Bonte D, Dahirel M. Dispersal: A central and independent trait in life history. Oikos. 2017;126(4):472–479. doi: 10.1111/oik.03801. - DOI