Skip to main page content
U.S. flag

An official website of the United States government

Dot gov

The .gov means it’s official.
Federal government websites often end in .gov or .mil. Before sharing sensitive information, make sure you’re on a federal government site.

Https

The site is secure.
The https:// ensures that you are connecting to the official website and that any information you provide is encrypted and transmitted securely.

Access keys NCBI Homepage MyNCBI Homepage Main Content Main Navigation
. 2025 Mar 4;20(3):e0319178.
doi: 10.1371/journal.pone.0319178. eCollection 2025.

Fairness in the multi-proposer-multi-responder ultimatum game

Affiliations

Fairness in the multi-proposer-multi-responder ultimatum game

Hana Krakovská et al. PLoS One. .

Abstract

The Ultimatum Game is conventionally formulated in the context of two players. Nonetheless, real-life scenarios often entail community interactions among numerous individuals. To address this, we introduce an extended version of the Ultimatum Game, called the Multi-Proposer-Multi-Responder Ultimatum Game. In this model, multiple responders and proposers simultaneously interact in a one-shot game, introducing competition both within proposers and within responders. We derive subgame-perfect Nash equilibria for all scenarios and explore how these non-trivial values might provide insight into proposal and rejection behaviour experimentally observed in the context of one vs. one Ultimatum Game. Additionally, by considering the asymptotic numbers of players, we propose two potential estimates for a "fair" threshold: either 31.8% or 36.8% of the pie (share) for the responder.

PubMed Disclaimer

Conflict of interest statement

The authors have declared that no competing interests exist.

Figures

Fig 1
Fig 1. Graphical example of the MPMR UG for the case of L = 3 responders and K = 2 proposers.
In the first stage, proposers announce their offers, prompting each responder to determine their selection strategy. In this scenario, responder 1 chooses a mixed strategy while the other two responders play pure strategies. In the second stage, it is probabilistically decided that responder 1 chooses proposer 1. Since two responders chose proposer 2 ,  another probabilistic realisation determines who gets paired with the proposer. In this case, responder 2 is unpaired, resulting in a zero payoff. Similarly, if one of the proposers (or both) would not be selected they would receive a zero payoff.
Fig 2
Fig 2. Numeric values of the proposers’ Nash equilibria and expected payoffs.
(A) Numeric values of offers from Eq (12). (B) Expected payoffs of the proposers. (C) Expected payoff of the responders. See Eq (13) for the formulas. The values are shown for varying numbers of responders and proposers.
Fig 3
Fig 3. The expected payoffs and offer levels for varying proposer-responder ratio c .
Here we show the expected payoff for proposers (blue), for responders (red dashed), the offer level (black) and 1-the offer level (black dashed) in subgame-perfect Nash equilibrium with respect to the proposer-responder ratio c, i.e. K = cL, in the large L limit (compare Eq (14) and Eq (15)). The differences between the offer and expected payoffs arise from “inefficiencies”. That is, with some probability some responders choose the same proposer and some proposers may not get chosen by any responder.
Fig 4
Fig 4. Comparison of theoretical predictions of proposers’ offers in the subgame-perfect Nash equilibrium and evolutionary simulation results.
On the left, we show the theoretical predictions derived in the previous sections, on the right the results of the evolutionary simulations for 9 different scenarios with varying numbers of proposers and responders.

References

    1. Guth W, Schmittberger R, Schwarze B. An experimental analysis of ultimatum bargaining. J Econ Behav Organiz. 1982;3(4):367–88.
    1. Gintis H. Game theory evolving: a problem-centered introduction to modeling strategic behavior. Princeton University Press; 2000.
    1. Camerer CF. Behavioral game theory: experiments in strategic interaction. Princeton University Press; 2011.
    1. Henrich J, Boyd R, Bowles S, Camerer C, Fehr E, Gintis H, et al. Economic man in cross-cultural perspective: Behavioral experiments in 15 small-scale societies. Behav Brain Sci. 2005;28(6):795–815. doi: 10.1017/s0140525x05000142 - DOI - PubMed
    1. Oosterbeek H, Sloof R, Van De Kuilen G. Cultural differences in ultimatum game experiments: Evidence from a meta-analysis. Exp Econ. 2004;7(2):171–88. doi: 10.1023/b:exec.0000026978.14316.74 - DOI

LinkOut - more resources